The scientific mind is not forever closed: it is merely intolerant of wasting time on the proposal of attention-seeking amateurs who are too lazy to master the simplest fundamentals of a science.Proceed forewarned. [editor]Garrett Hardin in Ecological Economics
![]() |
---|
![]() |
---|
![]() |
---|
"[Vannevar Bush] never flatly refused to satisfy a politician's curiosity, but rather dared him to comprehend the technical and military issues. Most politicos wisely kept their mouths shut." From a review of "Endless Frontier" by G. Pascal Zachary, Wall Street Journal, 10/21/97, A20.
In the past two years, a number of articles have appeared warning not only of a new oil crisis, but of the end of the oil era, as oil production inevitably peaks and declines due to inexorable geological forces. These include "Mideast Oil Forever?" by Joseph J. Romm and Charles B. Curtis and "Heading Off the Permanent Oil Crisis," by James J. MacKenzie, among others.
The profusion of articles on the subject is unfortunate, since the casual reader (and policy-maker) might conclude that the large number of articles have an equally large amount of research behind them. In truth, most of these are not actually about oil, but take the assumption that oil scarcity is imminent, especially outside the Middle East, and nearly all rely on a few pessimistic quotes from oil men, or recent work by one or two geologists using what is known as a "Hubbert approach." Most notable are the recent publication of the book The Coming Oil Crisis by Colin Campbell and the March 1998 Scientific American article "The End of Cheap Oil" by Colin J. Campbell and Jean H. Laherrere.
The gist of their argument is that most of the world's oil has already been found, as evidenced by the alleged lack of recent giant discoveries; Middle East reserves have been overstated for political reasons; actual total recoverable resources are only about 1.8 trillion barrels, not the 2.4 trillion barrels that others have estimated; existing fields will not continue to expand in size and production as others suggest; and most oil producing countries outside the Middle East are said to be near, if not past, their point of peak production, which occurs when 50% of total oil resources have been produced. Production is predicted to drop off steeply afterwards. Thus, they forecast that "The End of Cheap Oil" is at hand and prices will be rising shortly.
But there are several methods of judging research that don't involve time-consuming or labor-intensive analysis. For one thing, analysts who don't acknowledge either data or research which contradicts their theories are implying they can't explain inconsistencies or weakness in their work. Because in a complex system like world oil production, there is always some data which can support alternative viewpoints. Dry holes are always being drilled and new fields are always being found, and citing one or the other to support pessimism or optimism proves nothing.
A better way to test forecast validity is to look at the historical record, and particularly, examine work done by the person making the forecast in question. In 1992, I did precisely this to improve long-term oil price forecasting. The realization that the previous errors were due to forecasters assuming a 3% per year increase in real oil prices over the long-term made it possible to produce much more accurate forecasts.
In 1996, I published a piece discussing the various methods which were used to forecast oil supply, and argued that they, too, were flawed by certain repetitive errors, namely: 1) bias, and especially pessimism, since nearly every forecast has been too low since 1978, despite relying on price assumptions that were much too high; 2) similar forecasts for every region, despite different fiscal systems, drilling levels and/or the maturity of the industry, suggesting omitted variables; 3) misinterpretation of recoverable resources as total resources by using a point estimate instead of a dynamic variable, growing with technology change, infrastructure improvements, etc.; so that 4) there is a tendency for all national, regional or non-OPEC production forecasts to show a near-term peak and decline, which was always moved outward and higher in later forecasts (the opposite of price forecasts).
As an example, note the behavior of the U.S. Department of Energy's
production forecasts for the non-OPEC Third World, a region which, in aggregate,
has experienced very little drilling and shows no sign of peaking, causing
the forecasts to be repeatedly revised upwards. (Figure
1) I have numerous other such examples, for various countries and regions,
as well as the globe. Few, if any, have been too optimistic.
Subsequently, Campbell published an article in the December 1989 Noroil
which stated that
His
figure shows world oil production (including the Middle East) peaking in
the late 1980s, and dropping sharply, from about 58 mb/d to 45 mb/d, with
the comment that "Any short-term increase steepens subsequent decline."
He also shows prices rising to the low $20s (about $27 in 1997$) as "increasing
probability" with an "anticipated price leap from increased perception
of declining reserves, falling non-Middle East production, and falling
exports, esp. from USSR." He predicted this might cause oil prices to reach
$50/bbl (about $65 in 1997$) by 1994, then fluctuate around that level
to the end of the century.
"Most economic forecasts see relatively stable prices over the near
future followed by a ramp of modest increase to the end of the century.
But Figure
3 suggests that the slope of declining supply will become a precipice
if production is held at present levels, never mind increasing. When that
happens, a major leap in prices seems inevitable unless the major exporting
governments exercise deliberate restraint....Shortages seem to be inevitable
by the late 1990s, but knowledge of an impending supply shortfall may trigger
an earlier price response, as foreseen in the Figure."
That same year, my Oil Prices to 2000 was published, taking the contrary
view. I argued that most forecasts were too pessimistic about non-OPEC
production and predicted that inflation-adjusted prices would fall to 2000,
which the September 1989 Petroleum Economist correctly noted was "heretical".
Yet this proved quite accurate, as a comparison of forecasts from that
period shows (Figure
4) . (Later figures will compare production forecasts.) Since Campbell
(1989) includes only a graph of his price forecast, it is not shown here,
but by the mid-1990s, he showed prices fluctuating around $50/bbl, about
200% too high.
For example, except for Italy, Tunisia and Oman, in all of the countries where Campbell's forecast is too high, the upstream sector is controlled by national oil companies. This shows the importance of policy and economics, refuting the argument that geology alone determines long-term production profiles. If Campbell is said to be projecting possible, not actual production, so that his error on these countries should be disregarded, then it leaves a total "optimistic" error of only 106 tb/d, a trivial amount. This demonstrates clearly that his method is biased in a scientific sense, always producing forecasts which will tend to be too low.
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
In fact, what is remarkable is the similarity between Campbell's 1989, 1991 and 1997/98 forecasts (if one ignores the dates). Always, the peak is imminent. But this precisely conforms to the argument in Lynch (1996), namely that this method almost always produces a near-term peak, no matter when or where it is applied, and thus constantly needs to be revised upwards.
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
In his 12/29/97 OGJ article, he did present a number of small graphs
showing bell curves for a variety of countries, some which he described
as being past their depletion midpoint, some of which had not yet reached
it. These are shown in Table
2 , along with the depletion midpoint which he gave in his 1991 book,
and they reaffirm my earlier arguments. The fact that all of these countries
are predicted to peak by 2001 implies that there is a pessimistic bias
(#1 and 2 from Lynch 1996 above). And his having to move the depletion
midpoint out an average of 4 years for the countries which haven't peaked
supports the argument (#4 from Lynch 1996 above) that this method always
requires correction, and that the peak constantly needs to be revised to
a higher, later level.
Lynch (1996) argued that the Hubbert method fails because it takes
recoverable (not total) resources as fixed, and assumes that to be the
area under the curve of total production. When the estimate of the area
under the curve (resources) is increased, the entire increase must be applied
to future production. This is exactly what is happening with Campbell,
as Figure 15 shows. The errors in his 1991 forecast and the adjustments
he has made in his latest work are thus predicted by Lynch (1996). Campbell
has not provided an alternative explanation, merely ignored them. And as
Figure
18 shows, his forecast is well outside the mainstream.
Short-term prices will certainly fluctuate, and we will surely have more oil crises, since they are short-term events. Unfortunately, there is little doubt that the certain failure of the current Cassandras will be forgotten within a few years and a new round of alarms will be sounded. Hopefully, it will not receive the attention that the current (and previous) ones did, and even more hopefully, most governments and companies have already learned their lesson from the tens of billions of dollars wasted when others cried wolf during the 1970s.